1. Bengali
Khasis
and the first boundaries of Bangladesh
The watershed events that
marked the production of a modern boundary between present day Sylhet and Meghalaya started way back in the 1780s. There were two distinct sets
of violent conflicts on Sylhet’s
northern frontiers[1]. According to Ludden, both
escalated during the 1787 famine and ended abruptly in 1790. Though connected,
they had different origins and distinct implications. They fell on either side
of the boundary that would separate the later histories of Sylhet and Meghalaya (specifically Khasi and Jaintia Hills).
The first set of conflicts had begun before 1780. It focused sharply on Pandua and concerned control over commercial routes and resources in the high mountains (Khasi Hills) above this river port town. Present day Pandua lies in Meghalaya, largely forgotten. Yet this town played such a central role in the history of the Khasi Hills. Pandua was described by Robert Lindsay, the resident and Collector of Sylhet in the 1780s, as being, along with Jaintia(pur), Sylhet’s main port for trade with Assam. Ludden states that these conflicts involved East India Company officials, mountain Khasia Rajas and warriors, Bengali settlers and merchants, private European merchants of various nationalities, Bengali Khasias, and jungle zamindars.
In 1780, Lindsay was warmly
welcomed by mountain Khasia Rajas
(see Chapter 2) probably because they hoped that he would help them, and he
needed their help in return. Their alliance controlled Pandua
for 3 years, but in 1783, one of his former allies attacked Pandua and Lindsay brought sepoys to secure Pandua merchant assets, including
his own. For the next 5 years, a rough balance of power held at Pandua, where the East India Company
had enough force to protect trade and collect some revenue but not enough to
protect Europeans, who did business there through resident Bengali and Khasia
middlemen.
In 1788, as mountain peoples
(Khasias) recovered from famine, some
Khasia Rajas wanted to bring European
merchants back to Pandua, but other Khasia Rajas captured the town instead. Sepoys seized Pandua in 1789, but lost it a year later, when the East
India Company silently abandoned the idea of making Pandua part of Sylhet, and then sought instead to
foster mountain commerce across a strictly enforced state border between Khasia and
Sylhet territories. Prospects were
bright for this plan, because mountain trades had continued through Pandua during the previous decade
of hostilities, and resident merchants at Pandua could easily deliver all
desired commodities to buyers in the lowlands.
The second set of conflicts
occurred in jungles and farming frontiers below the mountains (Khasi Hills) down to the Surma River around Sunamganj and Chhatak. Local
conditions became turbulent after 1780, as hill trades increased on routes to Pandua,
while Omaid Rezah’s[2] authority declined, and
new settlers and investors like Gowar Hari Singh arrived with East India Company authority. Violence erupted in 1788,
dispersed rapidly, and focused periodically on markets (ganj) where
subsistence goods, especially salt and rice, came from villages and left for
the mountains (Khasi Hills).
Widespread conflict raged
for 2 years. It involved Khasia and Bengali Khasia merchants, who carried goods
to and from the mountains. Bengali
Khasias, who moved among high and low lands where they held various
proprietary interests, Bengali merchants,
villagers and zamindars, and Afghans and so-called “Moguls”; and the East India Company’s army.
Most residents got embroiled in conflicts. Zamindars,
talukdars, chaudhuris, tankadars, wadaddars, patwaris, and other local men
in the ranks of East India Company Raj joined the fray.
Ganga Singh, a Bengali Khasia leader, and
his relatives emerged as warrior Rajas,
whose mountain pathways provided routes of escape and supply, and who focused
particularly on controlling river routes. War ended in 1790, after Lieutenant
Cheape spread terror in the region. Ganga Singh probably surrendered, perhaps
to prevent more death among his people, and appears to have been influential in
securing local submission. Many surviving local officials rejoined the East
India Company ranks after prescribed
acts of contrition and terms of imprisonment.
In 1790, the East India Company
drew a new boundary below Pandua that institutionalized the
outcome of war in mountains around Pandua and
forests behind Sunamganj. This new
boundary of Bengal Presidency in Sylhet became a reality based on Khasia victories in the mountains and
British victories below. It ran along the
base of the mountains and bisected the route from Sunamganj to Pandua.
It marked the northern limit of British Bengal,
which only then extended indisputably to the mountains, and equally
indisputably, did not include Pandua.
The primary justification
for the boundary was that it secured East India Company territory against
threats to British authority posed by unregulated mobility between the mountains
(Khasi Hills) and plains (Sylhet). According to Ludden, the
English drew the boundary to restrict mobility and sever social bonds between
people in the mountains and lowlands. The boundary altered Sylhet’s geography by crimping mobility, defining the northern
mountains (Khasi Hills) as alien Khasia territory, making northern Khasias aliens in Sylhet, and defining all the farmland below as Bengali.
In the official culture of East
India Company Raj, the new boundary
separated “races” of Khasias and Bengalis. It restricted
“intercourse and intermarriages” that
produced the so-called “degenerate Race
called Bengalee Cosseahs.” As Lindsay’s
successor, John Willes, explained
most eloquently, state problems addressed by the new boundary did not arise
from the inherent character of the Khasia
“race,” but rather from Khasia and Bengali intermarriage, and hence from Khasia and Bengali alliances that threatened
the East India Company’s territorial order by mixing lowland popular culture
with the wild, unruly culture of the mountains (Khasi Hills), where people did not respect the symbols or comply with
the rituals of state authority.
The new state border became
a boundary of “free trade” that separated groups who could be and could not be
trusted by officials to obey the rules of the state. Willes began to concoct
this new commercial geography in September 1789, when he still hoped Sylhet might keep Pandua;
but a year later, that hope had vanished, when he detailed a plan to
manage limestone trades in the manner of the salt monopoly, as “one mode of preventing wars and disturbance
with numerous clans of independent barbarian borderers and on secondary view as
an aid toward the protection of the low country against these borderers.”
He did not want to limit
private trade in limestone and rejected the idea that “competition among European manufacturers of Chunam [was directly]
connected with the incursions and depredations of the Cosseahs,” because
merchant “advances seem to be made to inhabitants
of the lowlands bordering upon the Cosseah Country, who procure the stones and
in reality are contractors for the delivery of the stones to the
manufacturers.” But he did believe that, “a promiscuous intercourse with the Rajahs has been and will be
productive of constant disputes in the lowlands,” because,
“The mode of getting the stone in the first instance is by
purchasing a Stone Hill from Cosseah Rajahs. The Comars or Chunam manufacturers
are then permitted to break the Hill and draw the limestone from thence. In an
agreement formed between Rajahs and a European, which I laid before the Supreme
Board, it was expressed that the Cosseah Rajahs should support him in carrying
out his business against all opposition. In another agreement it was expressed
that one of the Cosseah Rajahs should receive duties in preference to another.
In other instances, I have known provisions for muskets and powder”.
He sought to “remedy this evil without taking the
management of the drawing of the stone,” by leaving “the power of trading with the bordering [lands of limestone supply]”
to Company servants, who would sell stone from the mountains to private
merchants in the lowlands. He then prohibited European merchants from
operating personally inside all Khasia territory,
including Jaintia and Cachar. To engage in limestone trades,
Europeans had now to procure a license from the Collector to buy stone only at Sunamganj or Companyganj (which seems to have been established specifically to
regulate mountain trades).
He prohibited Khasia traders from northern mountains (Khasi Hills) from operating personally
in Sylhet, but not Khasias merchants from Jaintia or Cachar; and he explained this distinction by saying,
“Wax, ivory, and iron principally from from Cutchar and Jointah from
whence limestone are not procured. But these articles as well as Mugadooties
are brought to sale in the lowlands by the Cosseah traders who are considered
as quiet and inoffensive and are not as some of the Cosseah Rajahs desirous of
living by oppression and plunder. The Cosseah traders have and ought to receive
encouragement [because] they are oppressed by every independent chief of a
little hill and are anxious to live on good terms with our government.”
The new boundary did not end
all troublesome travels between the mountains (Khasi Hills) and plains (Sylhet).
In 1793, during the East India Company’s wide-ranging confiscation of Bengali Khasia and Khasia land, the Tahsildar
of Zillah Bungong reported that Khasias had come and beheaded 5 people
and taken away women to the [Khasi] hills. Sepoys
then burned Khasia villages before Khasia Rajahs met the Collector and
convinced him this conflict continued an old struggle between some Bengalis in the plains and Khasias in the
hills, it appears, over land.
Convinced that the violence
had not involved unilateral Khasia aggression,
the Collector then pursued judicious discipline to prevent further conflict,
sending sepoys under orders not to use
their weapons to bring Khasia
suspects to Sylhet, where
the accused received individual treatment as criminal offenders. Another
telling incident occurred 2 years later, when Willes traveled to Pandua,
where he delivered customary presents to Khasia
rajas and then surprisingly marched sepoys on a sightseeing trip to a
famous cave nearby, apparently without local permission.
A fight broke out and Khasias gathered “in great force around [his] troops,” sending “arrows flying all around in every direction.” Despite wounds to his
men, none died, and Willes escaped
without injury. He described the event as “a
minor incident” and said that despite their “treachery and duplicity,” the Khasias
had overall been “remarkably peaceable.”
Nevertheless, while at Pandua, Willes “devised a scheme to punish [the] treacherous
Cosseah chief,” by having his village “at
the summit of a high mountain” burned. One sepoy died and others received wounds in this punitive action,
which must have met the approval of some Khasia
Rajas.
Willes explained to his superiors, alluding to local custom, that “Cosseahs cannot be allowed to believe [he]
retreated out of fear,” and that he had inflicted this punishment to
maintain peace, “in accord with precedent.”
Though the new boundary between Khasia mountains
and Sylhet District remained open for
ongoing mobility, it also marked a new phase in the geographical history of
state discipline and territorial order, which imposed a new regime of private
property rights in old forests north of the Surma
River.
This imposition entailed a
forceful, protracted partitioning of old agrarian domains, where shifting
cultivation, hunting, permanent farms, trading and fighting had mingled in
spaces of boundless mobility between mountains and plains, and where local
mixtures of proprietary cultures emerged in mixed Khasia and Bengali
environs. In 1780, mixtures of proprietary practices included local respect for
the authority of the East India Company, Omaid Rezah, clan leaders, zamindars, Khasia Rajas, and others.
Men like Ganga Singh worked
in this realm to create mixed proprietary interests in land, labour, crops, and
cash. After 1790, all this mixing faded away as the East India Company’s Sylhet property system extended up to
the new northern boundary. With the completion of the Hustabood and Bandobast
for the rest of the district, property rights had become more strictly tied to
taxation than ever before; and this new rigour, instead of old indulgences
designed to woo powerful locals, now encompassed the northern forests.
Four years after his 1789
tour of “devastated parganas,” Willes
declared all indulgence for their landowners should end, and they should now be
accountable for jamma on normal
terms, meaning their land could be sold for arrears. Instead of giving away tax-free grants of forest, as Willes had
proposed during the war, Collectors kept old tax rates in force and endeavoured
to sell defaulting estates at government auction to new investors.
Land buyers in northern
forests now entered a state-managed land market where, as in the case of
commerce, individual rights rested on ethnic classifications. The East India Company prohibited all Khasias
from owning land in Sylhet District,
on the grounds that all their legally owned land had all been acquired
illegally, and that they could never abandon alien mountain methods for
establishing property rights. Collectors then expropriated Khasia property.
Even major figures like Ganga
Singh must have either lost their land to become tenants and labourers, or
turned themselves into Bengalis, at
least for official purposes. In this context, the land market thrived, as
buyers acquired state-defined land rights to support the long, laborious
process of clearing jungle, creating new farms, attracting tenants and labourers,
establishing markets, and generating crops to sustain a growing population.
North of the Surma river, clearing jungle to make
farms involved clearing Khasias from
records of land rights and expelling them or making them tenants and labourers.
In August 1792, the first recorded auction of Khasia taluks went to Lal Barker. A year later, the Collector
reported that he had completed the sale of all the land expropriated from
rebellious villagers, except for a “trifling
remainder of Cosseah land.” Lal
Barker’s purchase typifies two
apparent patterns: most buyers bought very small parcels of land, and former Khasia land sold at much lower prices
than other land on auction, especially in “devastated parganas” toured by Willes in 1789.
The general reason for the
extreme cheapness of northern land on government auction appears to be that it
remained covered with jungles where substantial numbers of Khasias still lived. In addition,
high tax rates continued to plague potential investors. Jamma remained pegged to the productivity of cultivated land, and
thus to the jungle’s potential, rather than current productivity. Owners of
jungle found it difficult to expand cultivation, in part because property
rights rested on state tax demands poorly calibrated to encourage, let alone
subsidize, investment.
All this did not prevent
forest investments, but encouraged investors to concentrate on land already
farmed, which they might sell or let go on government auction, where they would
reap any excess in the sale price over arrears. Sale proceeds might
eventually go into clearing forest for new cultivation, but Collectors complained
constantly that investors concentrated attention only on already cultivated
land, despite much lower tax rates on forest.
All across Sylhet District, many more estates than
ever before went on auction in 1792 and 1793. Their jamma in general rose as their proportion of jungle declined, and
only a small number attracted no bidders, despite harsh floods in 1791 and 1793.
At the same time, however,
by 1797, tracts of land north of the Surma
river, formerly owned by Khasis
and Bengali Khasis, had been occupied
by Bengali cultivators, who “[had] become very willing and eager to enter
into regular engagements to pay Revenue.” Again saying that Khasias had held this land by force,
failed to bring it to cultivation, and rather “scared away farmers,” the Collector reported that after the East
India Company “secured the area and
confined Cosseahs to the hills,” peace came to the region along with people
who turned forest into farms. This land had not been included in the Bandobast and its cultivators were now
anxious to secure their rights, by having land duly recorded in their names.
Their total jamma, he said, would be
at most 6,000 Cawns, which “[could] be
used to defray the cost of Tannahs that defend district against Cosseahs.”
Thus it seems that in the 1800s, Sylhet’s northern boundary marked off Khasia mountain territory from a lowland
agrarian region of state authority where farming expanded primarily in and
around the small village family estates. In the surviving domains of larger
estates, north of the Surma river, however, new farms expanded
more slowly, leaving more old jungles in place for the pursuit of traditional Khasia ways of life.
Conclusion
The boundary of Bangladesh formed all at once in 1947,
but its oldest segment, separating Sylhet
and Meghalaya, indicates much older,
more complex, and diverse local histories in the borderlands, which carry
meanings quite distinct from meanings inherent in the singular, continuous line
we see on national maps.
National boundaries often
cover older boundaries, whose meanings have changed dramatically over time, and
all boundaries have different meanings for different people in different
places. National boundaries are sacrosanct symbols of sovereignty, but for
people who move across them routinely, these same boundaries often appear as
mere obstacles to mobility.
This popular experience
reflects a much older reality than national maps, because for most of human
history, states had little power to regulate mobility across their borders.
Before 1790, north-eastern frontiers of Bengal
remained as open to mobility as they had been during Mughal times and before.
Sylhet embraced an array of social
environments spanning mountains and plains that comprised a historical space
with a very long past and boundless geography.
In 1790, British military
victories in lowland forest frontiers of northern Sylhet and Khasia military victories in the
mountains above combined to produce the first boundary in the region that
endeavoured specifically to restrict mobility from one side to the other. This
political boundary became a social boundary on both sides.
Below the mountains, old Bengali boundaries acquired new
geographical forms and cultural meanings. Land rights authorized by the state
now defined all the local elites who owned bounded plots of agricultural property,
including farms and jungles. Khasias became
official aliens, disallowed from participating fully in what became for the
first time a definitively Bengali agrarian
territory.
The first boundary of Bangladesh thus defined Sylhet as a Bengali territory in British India, where alien Khasias might live and work but could
never really belong. Ironically, in present day Meghalaya, the reverse may be
true - Bengalis might live and work
there but can never really belong. Initially, and still today, this boundary
defines Bengalis and Khasias as peoples with separate
histories, homelands, and cultural identities, which mingle in the local
history of the borderlands, where each defines the other, and where the memory
of Bengali Khasias north of the Surma
river indicates a distinctive borderland cultural past outside the reach of
the national imagination.
[1] The
First Boundary of Bangladesh, on Sylhet’s Northern Frontiers,David Ludden, 26 June 2003,
For the Journal of the Asiatic Society of Bangladesh.
[2] Omaid Rezah’s family received
a Mughal jaghir in return for protecting Sylhet Sarkar against
Khasia warriors, and he was last in a
line of Mughal frontier commanders,
called Tankadars. Omaid Rezah was the
largest landholder in Sylhet and the only true zamindar in the district. Bengalee Cosseahs lived mostly inside Omaid Rezah’s jaghir.
This comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDelete